Abstract
The aim of present study was to explore existence of long-run association between consumption, income and investment implied by Balanced Growth proposition of Neo-classical-growth-model of the Solow and Swan (1956). Using quarterly data on consumption, income and investment from 1995q1 through 2018q4. The study have tested the balanced growth hypothesis for the Denmark. Using standard Vector-Auto-Regression technique of Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) analysed the output shocks to both consumption and investment. Although, there exists cointegration implying long run relationship, the results are not consistent with the balanced-growth-hypothesis (BGH) with given data sample for Denmark.
Key Words
Balanced Growth, Consumption, Investment, Output, cointegration, Time Series, Impulse Response, Variance Decomposition
JEL Codes:
C50, E21, F43, O47
Introduction
Balanced growth hypothesis has two “different meanings in economics Jargon. In macroeconomics, balanced growth occurs when output and capital stock grow at the same rate over time. In development economics, balanced growth refers to the simultaneous, coordinated expansion of several sectors of an economy”.
King et al., (1991) have analysed the BGH for US and found that cointegrating-relations amongst the real flow variables are consistent with the BGH and that for a three variable real model, innovations in the balanced growth component account for more than two thirds of the unpredictable variation in output in 2-5 years.
The concept of balanced growth hypothesis and its measurement occupies a pivotal place in macroeconomics with differing definitions and measuring strategies. It mentions an equilibrium in which major aggregates generally output and capital stock grow at same rate over time and real interest rate remains constant. Balanced growth is linked with constant-returns-to-scale in macroeconomics while for some economists it is positively related to increasing returns to scale. “Rosenstein-Rodan (1943)” argued that post-war-industrialization required coordinated investments across all industries. According to him, further expansion of different sectors is complementary because output of one sector increases the size of market for remaining sectors.
Murphy et al., (1989) formalized a multisector model using key ideas of balanced growth hypothesis by considering firms in individual sectors of economy adopt constant-returns-to scale-technologies found that technology becomes profitable for large scale markets and model generates a multiple equilibrium that may be Pareto-optimal.
Many studies including Kosobud et al., (1961) found evidence for the BGH in which output, investment and consumption exhibited positive trend in growth. Real business cycle models imply that a permanent shift in productivity leads to long-run equi-proportionate shifts in paths of output, consumption and investment with differential movements in consumption- investment and output and their dynamic adjustments.
The standard approach is to identify the lasting productivity-shocks as the shocks to common stochastic trend in consumption-investment and output using procedures used by “Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990)”. Balanced-growth model implies Y_t has a common stochastic-trend and the cointegrating space “ct –yt and It – yt”are I (0).
Literature Review
Solow and Swan (1956), in their contribution, argued that the driving force behind sustained economic growth was technological advancement. Solow (1957) estimated that only some 12.5% of the increased output per head in the United. States. over 1909 - 1949 was crdited to increases in capital / labour ratio (movements along the production function), with technological progress (upward movement of the production function) explaining the remaining 87.5% of the secular growth in productivity. He argued, also, that the pace of the upward shift in the production function tended to be roughly constant from year to year, albeit with a parametric shift mid-way through this period of observation that doubled the rate of productivity growth. These findings generated new debates - both theoretical and empirical.
Macroeconomics is concerned with solving the basic questions of what causes fluctuations in the output, unemployment, consumption and investment. Macroeconomic fluctuations can be described in terms of less-efficient response of economy to the changed tastes and technology shocks. Interest in economic growth has been a fundamental part of the economics since its beginning. In this context, study of the BG and convergence focuses on the modelling and empirical evidence that pertain to interrelated questions of growth of key macroeconomic variables in short and the long run. Macroeconomists over recent decades have been trying to articulate a framework capable of considering these questions. These attempts emerged in the form of a seminal contribution from Solow (1956) and Swan (1956) which has opened a growth-theory debate for a quarter of a century.
In a seminal paper titled “the dynamic effects of the aggregate demand and supply disturbances” concluded that fluctuations in GNP and unemployment were due to supply and demand disturbances. Demand disturbances having short run effects on output and unemployment due to nominal rigidities (sticky prices and Wages). The productivity disturbances affect the output in long-run and that both supply and demand disturbances had no long-run effect on unemployment. Decomposing macroeconomic fluctuations into temporary fluctuations and trend growth. Building on a Structural Vector Auto Regression (SVAR) in real GNP growth (?y) and the unemployment rate (U) using data sample from 1950:2 to 1987:4 in quarterly frequencies; their results accorded with the theoretical assumptions (Blanchard and Quah, 1989).
Blanchard’s (1989) paper “A Traditional interpretation of macroeconomic fluctuations” provide further insights into the working of key macroeconomic “variables including real output y, rate of unemployment U, Price level p, real wage w and nominal money supply M”. He concluded that fluctuations in the major macroeconomic variables can be interpreted in terms of shocks to demand, money, labour supply, productivity, price and wage setting. Supply-side shocks associated with decreases in nominal prices and wages play an significant role in medium to long-run while demand shock associated with the movements in output dominate fluctuations in the short run.
King et al., (1991) in their well-known empirical work on the sources of macroeconomic fluctuations used the monetary policy variables to get insights about theoretical ideas floated by Lucas (1975) and Barro (1976) have tested the BG hypothesis for the post-war United States data. Their results supported the BG theory but raised questions regarding the role of the productivity shock and the monetary shocks in explaining the fluctuations in the system of variables.
Lucas (1975) and Barro (1976) concluded that any interpretation of macroeconomic fluctuation is biased towards the monetary policy variables. Incorporating this finding of Lucas (1975) and Barro (1976), King et al., (1991) tested United States quarterly data on consumption, investment and output from 1949:1 to 1988:4 and 1954:1 to 1988:4 to get empirical support for BG. Their research finding based on a VECM approach raised some questions not only regarding the variables considered as the major source of macroeconomic fluctuations but also about the need for testing the validity of the claims of Barro (1976) by employing the monetary policy variables. Using Cobb-Douglas-production-function with constant-returns-to-scale, they checked the validity of their research finding by constructing a model with three real variables and then augmenting it with a set of three nominal variables. They found a substantial drop in explanatory power of the BG (“productivity”) shock from 70% to a 45% after including the nominal variables. This raised two questions; firstly, the BG shock is not the only source of variations in the macroeconomic fluctuations. Secondly, monetary policy factors are not successful in explaining the fluctuations over business cycle periods.
The contributions of the King et al., (1991) are consistent with the results of the Nelson and Plosser (1982) who revealed using a time series macroeconomic data for the United States that any macroeconomic model which rely on “monetary-disturbances as the source of the purely transitory fluctuations may never be successful in explaining a large fraction of the output variations and concluded that stochastic variations due to real factors are an essential element of any model of macroeconomic” fluctuations.
Hossain and Chung (1999) tested long run implications regarding one sector neoclassical growth theory for Australia, New Zealand, South Korea and Taiwan. They have used variance decomposition to examine the extent to which innovations in the common stochastic trend are able to explain the fluctuations in short run and they found favourable results. They found that the productivity shock alone is not capable of explaining all fluctuations in macro-data but investment innovations also play important role in the fluctuations in the common stochastic trend in the system (Whelan, 2004). Their application of exogeniety tests provided useful information about the variables. They found that stochastic trend for Taiwan data is due to innovations in investment not the innovations to output. The study further showed that only the Australian data is consistent with predictions of neoclassical growth theory whereas results are mixed for New Zealand, South Korea and Taiwan.
Whelan (2004) had revealed that addition of new “data from the U.S. National-Accounts rejects earlier widely-cited results that supported the one-sector model BG predictions. This is significant particularly because the idea of stable great ratios of real consumption or of real investment to real GDP has generally been considered a central stylized fact in macroeconomics. The fact that real investment appears to have a different long-run trend growth rate from real consumption in United. States data should have important implications for macroeconomic analysis, given that many empirical and theoretical studies take one-sector growth model as reference point for characterizing long-run behaviour of an economy”. This result of the Whelan (2004) is consistent with that obtained by the Hossain and Cheung, (1999).
In his seminal work, Mills (2001) used the Generalized-Impulse-Response-Functions (GIRF) of “Pesaran and Shin (1996, 1998) along with the Horvath and Watson (1995)” tests for known cointegrating-vectors and checked for the great ratio stationarity for the United Kingdom from 1955:1 through 1997:4. He found strong support for the existence of the GRS for the post-war UK quarterly data. With three dimensional-VAR frameworks of consumption-investment and income found that the GIRF converge to non-zero constants if consumption, investment and income are integrated of order one. The graphical display of the GIRF for the three real variables and two great ratios supported the theoretical assumptions where three variables converge to constants while the two great ratios to zero with the extremely slow convergence back to equilibrium in case of the investment: output ratio.
A re-interpretation of the great ratios, BG and stochastic trends came out in the shape of a work by Rafiq (2006) for the Euro Area. He has tried to answer the question” Are business cycles mainly due to permanent productivity shocks for the Euro Area?” He has replicated the work of the King et al., (1991) to reinvestigate robustness of results between Euro area and the United States. He has emphasized that role played by the monetary and inflation shocks were relatively in-significant. Extending the model with nominal variables showed very little impact on the results. His contribution to the literature includes the contention that real-interest-rate-innovations reflect that the central bank has played significant role in contributing to investment fluctuations and less to output fluctuations. He concluded that the Euro Area data is consistent with one common stochastic trend which was due to permanent productivity shocks and hence dominant source of the business cycle fluctuations (Khan et al., 2020) for the Euro Area.
Various empirical studies have investigated BG for different regions or countries. These studies have employed different data sets and methodologies to assess empirical support for this theory. The outcome of these studies remains, however, inconclusive. The empirical literature on BG and consequent great ratio stationarity (GRS) evolved in different dimensions including testing GRS “(Klein and Kosobud, 1961) and applying new time series techniques employing the concepts of unit roots and cointegration (King et al., 1991; Neusser, 1991; Serletis, 1994; Serletis and Krichel, 1995; Hossain and Chung, 1999; Mills, 2001; Harvey et al., 2003; Whelan, 2005)”. These studies examined long-run behaviour of consumption-investment and output – the component elements of the “great ratios”, and find mixed empirical support for a common rate of growth. More recently, echoing Solow’s (1957) assertion of the potential for parametric shifts in the rate of technological progress, the empirical literature has begun investigating BG and GRS with econometric methods that permit structural breaks in unit root and cointegration testing, but still with mixed results (Attfield and Temple, 2010; and Kemper et al., 2011).
Despite the large volume of research in this field, limited evidence on the validity of neoclassical growth theory in terms of testing the output per capita convergence (Khan and Daly, 2018) in leading European economies ignoring balanced growth hypothesis. This study will address these two gaps by extending the work of “King et al., (1991). Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990)” techniques will be employed for Denmark.
Some recent developments in the area of BGH investigations have reported different results for countries like China, Turkey and SAARC region countries (Li, et al., 1998; Li and Daly, 2009: Attifield and Temple, 2010; Khan, 2014: Khan &Daly, 2018).
Methodology, Data and Theoretical Background
We consider the formulation of a RBC model used King et al., (1988) with permanent productivity shocks, output Yt is produced via a usual constant returns to scale Cobb-Douglas production function:
Yt = ? t K? N1-? (1)
Log (Yt) = log (?t) + ?kt + (1-?) ? t (2)
Where “Kt is the capital stock and Nt represents labour input. ? t is the total factor productivity, ? t, follows a logarithmic random walk”:
Log (?t) = ?? + log (?t-1) + ?t (3)
Where the innovations, ?t ~ (0, ?2). “The ?? represent-average-rate of growth in productivity, ?t represents deviations of actual growth from this average.
Et log (?t+s) = Et-1 (?t+s) + ?t (4)
A “positive productivity shock raises the expected long-run growth path. There is a common stochastic trend in the logarithms of consumption, investment, and output. The stochastic trend is log ((?t)/?, and its growth rate is (??+ ?t)/ ?, the analogue of the deterministic model’s common growth – rate restriction, ??/?. With common stochastic trends, the ratios Ct /Yt and It /Yt become stationary stochastic processes”. Balanced growth implies that Ct/Yt and It/Yt are stable ratios. Therefore, in logs, ct-yt and it – yt must be I (0). The random walk in log(?t) implies Yt ~ I (1) and since ct-yt and it-yt are I(0), therefore ct and it must be I(1) but the vector zt= [ ct, it , yt ] cointegrates.
The specification with wold representation becomes;
?Zt = ? + c(L) ?t (5)
Where “?t is the vector of one-step-ahead linear forecast errors in Zt. The ?ts is are serially uncorrelated with mean zero and covariance matrix ?e. considering a structural-model of form”
?Zt = u + ?(L) ?t (6)
Where “?t is an n X x1 vector of serially uncorrelated structural disturbances with a mean of zero and a covariance matrix ?t”. Alternatively, these identifying restrictions can be imposed by rewriting the model in terms of the stationary variables Zt = (?yt, ct - yt, it - yt)'. Theory of the real business cycle with balanced growth hypothesis states that for three variables (ct, it, yt) and one common stochastic trend – productivity shocks implies, n=3 and n-r = 1, so, there are r=2 cointegrating vectors. We can restrict b1 = -1 and b2 = -1.
Assume Ct
Zt = It (7)
Yt
Assume ct, yt, and It be natural logarithms of consumption, income and investment respectively and let Zt= (ct, yt, It). If zt is I (1) and great ratios ct – yt and it – yt are stable (Stationary), then a VECM may be written as;
?Zt = ??'zt-1 + ?1?zt-1+?k ?zt-2 + + ?t (8)
Where ?zt= zt – zt-1 while ?t is a GZaussian error
?11 ?12 0 1 0 -1
? = ?21 ?22 ; ?` = 0 0 1 -1
?3`1 ?32
Data Properties and VAR Specification
Empirical Results
The empirical results of the structural VAR are presented and discussed
in this section. At first the VAR specification is introduced. Using the IRF
and variance decompositions the properties of the identified structural shocks
are analysed.
Table
1. Unit Root Tests Results
Series |
Levels |
First-differences |
Dec. |
|||
C |
C
& T |
Dec. |
C |
C
& T |
||
Y |
1.6181 |
1.1700 |
N.S. |
-6.55 |
-7.95 |
S |
I |
-0.6471 |
-3.021 |
N.S. |
-5.30 |
-5.51 |
S |
C |
-0.1689 |
-1.7120 |
N.S. |
-8.69 |
-4.73 |
S |
Note: ** indicate significance at 5%
The Lag-order of VAR model several “lag order selection criteria along
with the Likelihood ratio (LR) tests for parameters reduction were performed.
Where Akaike criteria (AIC), Schwartz Bayesian criterion (SBC), the
Hannan-Quinn (HQ), Final prediction error (FPE)” all reported five lags in
Table 2 below:
Table 2. Lag Order Selection Criteria
Lag |
LogL |
LR |
FPE |
AIC |
SC |
HQ |
0 |
520.5334 |
NA |
1.67e-09 |
-11.69394 |
-11.52503 |
-11.62589 |
1 |
606.0790 |
161.3700 |
2.94e-10 |
-13.43361 |
-13.01134 |
-13.26349 |
2 |
625.0308 |
34.45794 |
2.35e-10 |
-13.65979 |
-12.98415 |
-13.38759 |
3 |
648.1884 |
40.52583 |
1.71e-10 |
-13.98156 |
-13.05255 |
-13.60728 |
4 |
701.8398 |
90.23187 |
6.21e-11 |
-14.99636 |
-13.81399 |
-14.52001 |
5 |
723.2923 |
34.61650* |
4.71e-11* |
-15.27937* |
-13.84364* |
-14.70095* |
6 |
728.3059 |
7.748350 |
5.21e-11 |
-15.18877 |
-13.49968 |
-14.50828 |
7 |
734.4488 |
9.074702 |
5.63e-11 |
-15.12384 |
-13.18138 |
-14.34127 |
8 |
743.4564 |
12.69255 |
5.73e-11 |
-15.12401 |
-12.92819 |
-14.23937 |
LR: sequential
modified LR test statistic (each test at 5% level)
FPE: Final prediction
error
AIC: Akaike
information criterion
SC: Schwarz
information criterion
HQ: Hannan-Quinn
information criterion
Note: * indicates lag order selected by the criterion
The VECM is specified by allowing a constant and trend in both the I (0)
and the I(1) components, model is estimated using five lags. The VAR-model
therefore was estimated with a constant, seasonal trend and five lags. The
cointegration vectors can be identified by imposing linear restrictions on the
long run parameters of the VECM and testing these restrictions by likelihood
ratio tests. The VAR-model based on equations (2) and (3) can be estimated
subject to the cointegrating restrictions.
Table 3. Johansen Cointegration Test for Zt = (yt, ct, it)
Null Hypothesis |
Trace statistics |
Critical Values** at 5% |
Maximum-Eigen value statistics |
Critical values 5% |
Prob. Values |
r= 0 |
57.21** |
35.19 |
38.09** |
22.29 |
0.0239 |
r =1 |
19.11 |
20.26 |
14.21 |
15.89 |
0.0037 |
Note: ** indicates rejection of null hypothesis and significance at 5%
The Johanson trace-test for cointegration significantly indicates the
existence of one cointegrating vector. The Trace statistic value is 57.21 at
r=0 which clearly is greater than critical values of 35.19 at 5% level. At r=1,
the trace test value 19.11 of less than critical value of 20.26 at 5% to acceptance of null hypothesis
at r=1. i.e there is one cointegrating vector.
The Maximum Eigen value test statistic values given in table 3 shows
that computed value of test- statistics 38.09809 is greater than the critical
values at 5% leads to rejection of null-hypothesis. While at r =1, the maximum
Eigen value test statistic is 14.22 which is smaller than critical value of
15.89 at 5% level of significance leading to acceptance of null-hypothesis that
there exists at most one cointegrating vector.
To compute the likelihood ratio test, we use
the system of log likelihood from this estimation for the restricted (LR) and
use the log likelihood from the case where r = 1 in the Johansen cointegration
test results and call this unrestricted (LU).
Log Likelihood (Unrestricted) = 733.48
Log Likelihood (Restricted) = 718.11
?2 = 2 (LU-LR) = 30.74
?2 (4, 0.05) = 9.49
Table
4. Wald Test of BG restrictions for Denmark
Chi-square(n-k)
d.f |
Probability |
Critical
values |
Decision |
14.3643 |
0.0007 |
5.99 |
Reject |
Table 4 above shows
that BG restrictions have been rejected for Denmark, thus confirming results
from cointegration analysis. In the unrestricted system, there are four free
parameters to estimate. On the other hand, in the system where we imposed
over-identifying restrictions, there are no free parameters. Hence, we imposed
four restrictions. The calculated value of which is 30.73 greater than
critical value of 9.49 leading to rejection of null hypothesis. This result indicates that the
restrictions do not hold for the balanced growth hypothesis. This result shows
that there is no cointegrating relationships between three flow variables and
that our data yields inconsistent results with the balanced growth hypothesis
theory.
Structural Identification
The impulse response functions show the dynamic reactions of
consumptions and investment to a standard deviation shock to real output Yt.
The vertical axis refers to the log of the variables considered while the
horizontal axis indicates the time horizon in quarters. The IRF depicts the
different impacts of income shocks on consumption and investment. The observed
dynamic response of the variables matches the predictions of the BGH. A
positive shock induces a permanent increase in the level of the real output. The impulse responses and the Variance
decomposition is shown in figures 1, (2) and (3).
Figure 1
Response to Cholesky one S.D innovations _+2S.E.
Figure 2
Variancede Compositions
Figure 3
Response to Cholesky one S.D Innovations
Conclusion
We have analysed the properties of the macroeconomic data of Denmark to assess observed significance of the standard RBC models with productivity-shocks. We have examined the long run relationship between income, consumption and investment using quarterly data for period 1995q1 up to 2018q4. Our empirical investigation consists of the application of cointegration analysis to ascertain the long run relationship between three flow variables. The cointegration analysis shows that although there exists long run relationship but results obtained are in-consistent with Balanced Growth Hypothesis for data sample used for Denmark. Future studies can focus on reinvestigating balanced growth hypothesis and Great Ratio stationarity taking into account, dynamics and structural breaks for different group of countries including Pakistan.
References
- Asafu-Adjaye, J. (2000). The relationship between energy consumption, energy prices and economic growth: time series evidence from Asian developing countries. Energy economics, 22(6), 615-625.
- Attfield, C. L. (2003). Balanced Growth and Output Convergence in Europe. University of Bristol, Department of Economics.
- Barro, R. J., (1976). Rational Expectations and the Role of Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 2(1), 1-32.
- Blanchard, O. J., & Quah, D. (1989). The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances. American Economic Review, 79(4), 655-
- Blanchard, O. J., (1989). A Traditional Interpretation of Macroeconomic Fluctuations. American Economic Review, 79(5), 1146-1164.
- Charnvitayapong, K., & Kandil, M. (1995). On the role of money in real business-cycle models. Applied Economics, 27(12), 1187-1199.
- Dickey, D. A., & Fuller, W. (1979). Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74(366), pp. 427-431.
- Enders, W. (1995). Applied Econometric Time Series, Wiley, New York.
- Enders, W. (2008). Applied econometric time series. John Wiley & Sons
- Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis. Pearson Education India.
- Hafer, R. W., & Dennis, W. J. (1991). The Demand for Money in the United States: Evidence from Cointegration; Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 23, No. 2, (May, 1991), pp. 155- 168.
- Harvey, D. I., Leybourne, S. J., & Newbold, P. (2003). How Great Are the Great Ratios? Applied Economics, 35(2), 163-177.
- Hossain, F., & Chung, P. J. (1999). Long-run implications of neoclassical growth models: empirical evidence from Australia, New Zealand, South Korea and Taiwan. Applied Economics, 31(9), 1073-1082.
- Johansen, S. (1988). Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12(2), pp. 231-254.
- Johansen, S. (1991). Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica: journal of the Econometric Society, 1551-1580.
- Johansen, S., & Juselius, K. (1990). Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on CointegrationWith Applications to the Demand for Money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52(2), pp. 169-210.
- Jones, L. E., & Henry, E. S. (2000). Growth and Business Cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 271.
- Kemper, N., Herzer, D., & Zamparelli, L. (2011). Balanced Growth and Structural Breaks: Evidence for Germany. Empirical Economics, 40(2), pp. 409-424.
- Khan, G. Y. (2014). Applicability of neo-classical growth theory to the SAARC5 countries: an empirical assessment (Doctoral dissertation, Kingston University).
- Khan, G. Y., Bashir, M., & Mehboob, S. (2019). Structural breaks and unit roots in selected macroeconomic series: Evidence from Pakistan. Paradigms, 13(2), 65-69.
- Khan, G. Y., Khalil, I., Mehboob, S., Rauf, A., & Abbasi, A. B. (2020). Questing Business Cycle Synchronization among South Asia in Pre and Post SAARC Establishment: An Empirical Investigation. European Online Journal of Natural and Social Sciences, 9(3), pp-628.
Cite this article
-
APA : Khan, G. Y., Anwar, M. M., & Anwar, A. (2020). Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark. Global Social Sciences Review, V(III), 64-74. https://doi.org/10.31703/gssr.2020(V-III).07
-
CHICAGO : Khan, Ghulam Yahya, Muhammad Masood Anwar, and Aftab Anwar. 2020. "Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark." Global Social Sciences Review, V (III): 64-74 doi: 10.31703/gssr.2020(V-III).07
-
HARVARD : KHAN, G. Y., ANWAR, M. M. & ANWAR, A. 2020. Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark. Global Social Sciences Review, V, 64-74.
-
MHRA : Khan, Ghulam Yahya, Muhammad Masood Anwar, and Aftab Anwar. 2020. "Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark." Global Social Sciences Review, V: 64-74
-
MLA : Khan, Ghulam Yahya, Muhammad Masood Anwar, and Aftab Anwar. "Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark." Global Social Sciences Review, V.III (2020): 64-74 Print.
-
OXFORD : Khan, Ghulam Yahya, Anwar, Muhammad Masood, and Anwar, Aftab (2020), "Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark", Global Social Sciences Review, V (III), 64-74
-
TURABIAN : Khan, Ghulam Yahya, Muhammad Masood Anwar, and Aftab Anwar. "Exploring the Presence of Balanced Growth: Empirical Evidence from Denmark." Global Social Sciences Review V, no. III (2020): 64-74. https://doi.org/10.31703/gssr.2020(V-III).07